Capitalism - A System of Competition?
Capitalism
has often been described by as “a system of competition” by its
adversaries, or a system “based on competition.” Naturally, this
assertion is usually coupled with a spirited oration on how this
“tooth n’ nail” competition psychologically corrupts us –
pitting man against man in a “race to the bottom.”
Many
of capitalism’s most vocal advocates have, themselves, imbibed this
premise uncritically. They leap to a fervent defences of competition,
extolling its virtues – real or perceived. In my view this is a
mistake. To accept without evaluation the presupposition that
capitalism is a system of competition – in contrast to other
hypothetical systems of cooperation (namely socialism and communism)
– is to frame the very debate itself in leftist terms and play the
game on an unfairly tilted game-board.
Competition
is Fierce for Government-Controlled Resources
This
is not to say that those who defend competition do not raise some
worthy points. For example: If not competition, then what is the
alternative? Is there to be one central provider of each good and
service available who gets to decide on our behalf how it is best to
be produced and then allocated? Add to that, that if competition is
wrong in the market, then why not in the political sphere? Surely
democracy is out of the question if competition is a corrupting
factor, because what do political candidates do if not compete for
office? Think of the competition this generates between political
parties, not to mention the ensuing competition between firms and
individuals for preferential treatment from politicians and
legislators, competition between lobbyists, think-tanks, and voters,
to receive benefits out of the public purse. If the free and
voluntary section of society is a system of competition, how much
more so is government? Surely democracy is a “system of
competition.” Politicians are competing for the very machinations
of control in our society. For the right to pass and enforce laws
which apply to everyone (whether they agree with them or not) and to
force them to pay for their enforcement. They are not simply
competing for market share where the winner of the competition is the
one that satisfies the most demand. We can sidestep the more mundane
economic arguments in favour of competition for the moment, such as
the case that it increases efficiency and cheapens goods while
driving innovation, as we are all familiar with them already.
Capitalism
is a System of Voluntary Exchange
Nonetheless,
parsing what is essentially a sociological debate – a meditation
upon the effects of an economic environment upon the soul of man –
in socialist terms; basing it upon left-wing premises without
examining their foundation is to cede too much ground. A comical
equivalent would be for a leftist responding to the clichéd
assertion of the American right that “Hitler was a Socialist!” by
arguing that many of his labour policies were successful in improving
social conditions for the working class.
This
is not to say that competition is necessarily an evil either. The
problem lies in defining capitalism as “a system of competition”
- in comparison to other systems which are somehow “cooperative”;
that is a rhetorical ploy. Those who profess it may honestly believe
it to be so, but it’s not true. Capitalism is not “a system of
competition” any more than any other system. Capitalism (at least
in its free-market, laissez faire ideal) is a system of the
voluntary exchange of goods and services in the absence of
physical coercion, theft, compulsion or fraud, predicated upon
the fundamental right to own and accumulate property.
Or,
for brevity:
Capitalism is a system of voluntary exchange,
predicated upon the right to own property.
One might even venture, therefore, that capitalism is a system of
voluntary cooperation.
Granted,
this definition still leaves room to debate the morality of
accumulating property. Or perhaps whether the “negative” right to
ownership when it comes to the rich should take precedence over the
“positive” right to healthcare or education at their expense when
it comes to the poor. We can even debate whether the relationship
between capitalists and their employees are really free of coercion
given the power disparity between the two groups. Indeed these are
debates I delight in exploring further. However, there is no
justification for defining capitalism as a
system based upon
competition.
Because
Scarcity is a Fact of Life, Competition will Exist under Any System
The
reason for this is that while the voluntary exchange of
goods and services may give rise to a certain
amount of competition, competition does not give rise to the
voluntary exchange of goods and services.
Scarcity does. In any
situation of scarcity of resources, there is bound to be some form of
competition over those resources (as well as over how those resources
are allocated). To exemplify
the mistake that is being
made here, consider
the uncontroversial
statement: “The fact that
things exist gives rise to motion.”; Now,
if I were
to conclude
that because of this,
“motion itself gives rise
to the material world,” that
would be a weird conclusion to reach. Motion
is a feature of the material world, not what defines it or gives rise
to it. Similarly, competition
is a feature found within a
capitalist economy,
but it is not its defining feature, nor
is it only a feature
of capitalism…
If
we have a system that allows voluntary exchange, some competition is
bound to arise out of that, but that would happen under any system.
Even if you had a completely communistic society, which was centrally
planned and involved no exchange of money whatsoever, people’s time
would still be limited. If you were a film maker in this society, you
would probably want as many people to see your films as possible. As
would every other film-maker. That
would put you at least somewhat in competition with them. Does this
mean that communism, too, is a system of competition? Certainly you
would be competing for the only customer – the sponsorship of the
state. Corruption and cronyism would surely be
the result. Who
gets their film made and who doesn’t? Who allocates the highly
desirable job of being a film-maker over the undesirable job of being
a street-sweeper or refuse collector, and how can their favour be
courted? The competition will commence, but instead of being decided
by the free and voluntary exchange of film-goers, investors and
film-makers it will be decided by someone else, I would argue, in a
rather more authoritarian fashion.
(For
a particularly vivid and
chilling illustration of how
communism substitutes market competition over customers [which
is at least tied to the provision of desirable services]
for the completely unmeritocratic competition over
gaining favour from the corrupt power structure of the state, I refer
the reader to Ayn Rand’s first novel, We The Living.)
Competition
is a feature of living in a world of scarcity and
would exist in any system.
Socialism cannot do away with competition
– nor can any other system.
Therefore
it is wrong, both
logically
and polemically, to define capitalism as “a system of competition”
in contrast to socialism;
let alone define communism – a system where individuals will have
to compete for the favour of authorities who make decisions on their
behalf – as a system of
cooperation.
Scarcity
Means Competition Extends Beyond the Economy
The
implications of these facts reach into
any circumstances of
scarcity beyond
the economy. For example,
supposing
two friends each invite
me over to dinner
of an evening, I might have
to make a choice between their
invitations which will result
in one of them losing out on my company. Does this then mean that
friendship is a system of competition?
We
can’t see all of our friends all of the time, or even all of them
at the same time. Even if we do, we are bound to have to split our
attention between them. In addition to that we can only maintain so
many close friendships at once, and we definitely can’t be friends
with everyone. All of this means that inevitably we have to make
choices. We each make decisions on who to make and maintain
friendships with based upon our value judgements, conscious or
unconscious. Perhaps based on how happy we feel around them, how long
we have known one another, how much we have in common, how much we
trust someone or how loyal they have shown themselves to be, how much
they educate, enrich or enlighten us, or perhaps based upon what
roles roles they allow us to fulfil in their lives. There can be
countless other reasons. The fact is we decide. People who feel that
they will benefit from our company, for whatever reason, will make
attempts to spend time with us. We will invariably begin to make
choices on who to spend time with based upon our values, schedule,
and what other activities we are willing sacrifice to see them. These
are basic facts of life, but they hardly make friendship a system of
competition.
Similarly,
on the market, our time and resources are limited. We make
value-based judgements about choices of products and services to
consume based upon what utility we think they will bring to us,
sacrificing some options to others. Maybe we will choose a coffee
shop based on which has the best tasting coffee, or maybe based on
which provides the nicest atmosphere, or maybe based on which is
closest, or where the customer service is best, or which is the
cheapest, or which we have gone to the longest and therefore find
familiar, or perhaps even based on which we think has the best ethos
– for example, because they are a social enterprise that only sells
fair trade produce and deliberately seeks to employ and train
disadvantaged people. The fact is we decide. Each service provider
believes they will benefit from our custom and will make attempts to
attract us, placing an upward pressure on the quality of services and
a downward pressure on price which we may correctly identify as a
form of competition. Since human beings are not infallible, sometimes
someone might buy a coffee that they don’t end up liking, but over
the long term the competition is likely to be won by the satisfaction
of customers.
Free
to Choose
The
miraculous wonder we miss when we focus our attention upon the
competition which derives from choice is the ability to choose
itself. For example, supposing two commercial events are being held
on the same evening. Each perspective patron will want to choose
whichever event appeals to them the most, and for whatever reasons
they choose based upon what they value in an event. Now, to simply
mention that these events are “in competition” would be to
completely miss the crucial point that event-goers (who are in the
majority compared to event-organizers) have a choice of two events
which they may prefer to go to one of rather than one alone.
There
is no necessity for competition implicit in the market either. If
both events are in jeopardy due to a lack of patrons, then their
organizers can always put their heads together and create one bigger,
better event. Or they can choose distinct themes that are aimed at
different audiences, or perhaps they will agree that it would be in
their interests if one of them moved their event to a different
night, and they could cross-promote one another. This is part of the
free choice the market affords, unless the government has passed laws
against it, calling it “collusion.”
The
defining feature of the market, clearly, is not competition, but
choice. The freedom to choose. It is only when event organizers can
go to the government to force people to buy tickets, or shut down
other events, or get preferential legislation passed to make it
easier for them to advertise, or regulate the market so tightly that
only established events-managers can survive, that we see competition
become the dominant force. Coercion has entered the market which is
no longer free. This is not free market capitalism but what we
observe in many sectors of our society today – crony capitalism, or
“neo-liberalism” as some may call it. (Unfortunately the failings
of “neo-liberalism” are endlessly pinned on the market economy
itself rather than the state’s nefarious influence in the market.)
It
is worth mentioning that there is actually far more cooperation
involved in providing people with goods and services than
competition. You have to cooperate with buyers, sellers, managers,
employees, suppliers, customers, advertisers, promoters, marketers,
collective buyers, and so on. Leonard E. Read (1898-1983), founder
of the Foundation for Economic Education, illustrated this in his
most famous essay, I, Pencil, first published in 1958. In it
he noted that not a single person on the face of this earth knows how
to make a pencil. He goes onto explain that the cedarwood is sourced
from Oregon and the logs milled in California. The graphite is mined
in Ceylon, mixed with clay from Mississippi, then treated with a hot
mixture which includes candelilla wax from Mexico to increase its
strength and smoothness. The six coats of lacquer come separately
from the growers of castor beans and the refiners of castor oil. In
fact, when you include those who manufacture and transport the
equipment involved in these processes you cannot help but marvel at
the fact that millions of people have a hand in its creation. They
are working in concert, in cooperation, and as a result you can get a
pencil for pennies.
To
the extent that it is free, the self-interest of the producer is
subordinated to the hardly antisocial end of meeting the desires of
others. A producer wins the competition only by organising a vast
degree of cooperation in the service of satisfying the demand of
consumers. This means producing things that regular people like you
and I value enough to part with their scarce resources for. To the
extent the government interferes in the market, firms are enticed to
compete over government contracts, subsidies, preferential
legislations, and so forth. This is a corrupting factor in the market
as companies no longer have to focus on serving consumers but doing
whatever it takes to beguile officials. Sometimes that may well be
providing the best service, but this becomes far more likely as the
end user is no longer the buyer. Instead they may lobby, bribe, or
bait with promises of high paying positions for officials after they
leave office. In my book Universal Basic Income – For and
Against I note that according to
The Sunlight Foundation,
a non-partisan, non-profit organization that aims to make government
more accountable and transparent, “For each of the 5.8 billion
dollars spent by America's 200 most politically active corporations
between 2007 and 2012 on federal lobbying and campaign contributions
they got $741 in return in kickbacks and benefits. This poses a
tremendous problem because as soon as it becomes more profitable for
a business to lobby the government than serve their customers then
lobbying will become their top priority. This is why government is
often a corrupting actor in the economy rather than a referee. The
mutual benefit of politicians and big business getting in bed
together often outweigh those of serving the public. These
incentives drive companies to misallocate resources by making
products that the general public doesn't want profitable, and
products that they do unprofitable. In other words, the government
has become the client of
these corporations rather
than their customers.” The
competition has turned sour.
Those
free-market advocates who extol the virtues of competition may point
out that every service provider is, in one sense, actually competing
with every other product that someone can possibly conceive of buying
with their money, and argue that is a good thing as encourages firms
to really try their best to create things that will please people in
order to earn their cash and do business with them. Still, it cannot
be said that capitalism is a system of competition – because
competition is not the basis of the system, but choice. The freedom
of consumers to choose gives rise to trial and error between
competing service-providers attempting to draw a profit by catering
broadly to as many consumers as possible or narrowly to meet certain
niches depending upon their expertise and predilections. As human
desires are infinite, there will likely always be incrementally more
beneficial ways of meeting those desires, and thus infinite scope for
innovation. What the market allows is for different producers to fill
different niches. Buyers are able to compare the relative merits and
drawbacks of competing products and vote with their cash on which
they feel will better meet their needs according to their own values.
Producers themselves are able to observe innovations in the
marketplace and attempt to improve upon whichever products or
services are already available. Customers will ultimately be the
arbitrators of which models are successful and which will be weeded
out the market. While there is clearly some competition in this
process, overall it is a system of cooperation between buyers and
sellers to reach a mutually satisfying voluntary exchange. In
comparison to a centrally planned economy (or sector of an economy)
where the amount of trial and error is very limited, and the state
must roll out a one-size-fits-all solution scarcely tested against
other possible solutions – a little competition between service
producers might be worthwhile in exchange for a greater degree of
autonomy and cooperative communication between service users and
service providers which takes the form of supply and demand.
The
beauty of the free market, when it is allowed to function, it that it
is a constantly self-correcting and self-optimising system. Producers
can reflect upon what is available and look for gaps in the market,
or improvements upon existing services, and the public will quickly
be able to provide signals of what is serving them and what is not by
which variations they choose to part with their money for. Over time
this leads to a general improvement in the standard of service
available to them and decrease in cost which is probably why most of
the products we buy are pretty decent. If someone sells a faulty
watch then we have somewhere else to go for watches. If we did away
with choice in the name of eliminating competition, if there was a
design flaw in one watch it would have already been rolled out to
every store and it would be too late. What is more if someone could
think of any small way to make the watch better, more accurate, more
durable, more energy efficient, the new model would probably not hit
the market for fear of someone making another improvement upon it
making all of those obsolete as well.
The
Primary Feature of Capitalism is Choice, Not Competition
So
to review, because people make choices with scarce resources and
limited time, competition will be an inherent part of any economic
system so long as there is scarcity. The primary feature of free
market capitalism is not competition, but choice. Rather than
moderate the amount of competition in an economy, state intervention
will replace competition to serve customers on a voluntary basis with
competition over gaining the favour of whoever is responsible for
allocating resources within government. Instead of competing to serve
their customers as best as they possibly can to achieve the biggest
market share – firms can, will, and do, compete for government
favours, and to have their products “rolled out” by the state to
as many people as they can using public funds or subsidies out of the
public purse. This is where the real “tooth and nail” begins.
I read this article this morning on Mises.org. Absolutely brilliant! I have been studying economics as an amateur for sometime and fell into the very trap you discuss about calling it a system of competition. This is the first time I have seen someone write about it like this. Excellent!
ReplyDeleteGreetings Mr. Sammeroff,
ReplyDeleteSome 2 years ago, I sent out an Economics Challenge to the Mises Organization offering $10,000 for the flaw in a simple proof for the idea that it makes no difference if a community has its government tax or borrow from resident citizens to fund public expenditures. But there are huge costs in Taxation, in waste and in its deterrent effect, that disappear with Borrowing. So a community is always better off having its government borrow than tax.
The video is here: https://vimeo.com/179463643
You may also view it on my $10,000 Public Finance Challenge Page here: http://www.economart.ca/challenges/
Why is this so?
There is an errant premise in Public Finance Theory. Everyone knows it, but fails to act on it.
Let us say the US Govt. spends $4T per year. $3T taxed and $1T borrowed. All would say the deficit is $1T. Wrong!
How much did the Govt. contribute to its expenditures? The answer is nothing. The government has no money, no assets, no income. Thus, the true deficit is every dime spent. Total US public debt, unaccounted though it is, is every dime spent since the US Gov't's inception.
Taxpayers, or rather resident citizens, or rather the combined property, assets and incomes of resident citizens, what I call That Which Funds Government (TWFG), funds government - all of it. To answer the big questions in Public Finance, one must visualize the box of TWFG and study it rather than the finances of an entity that doesn't have any money. In the video I have done that. No difference between taxing and borrowing. A sum, say $50, leaves TWFG whether taxed or borrowed. The 3 operations in borrowing: adding a public debt, adding interest to it and repaying the public debt do not alter in any way the aggregates of assets and liabilities of TWFG. Thus, a community should have its govt. always borrow and never tax because of Taxation's inherent costs.
A graduate student presented a refutation of my proposal in the form of a variation of Barro's Ricardian Equivalance Theorem.
I answered with my own refutation of Barro's conclusion.
You may find that here on my blog page: http://www.economart.ca/ricardo/
In the movie, the Big Short, about 20 people, many outsiders, saw the approaching financial calamity in housing bonds in 2007 whilst the many thousands working directly in that business on Wall Street did not. Why was that?
There is a lot of discarded public debt in the world that would become very valuable if just one municipality, state, province, or nation in the world were to follow the prescription.
Regards,
Gary Marshall
So is possible that HIV Disease can be cured because I have been scammed so many times not until I came across this great man herbalist Dr Akhigbe who helped me at first I never believe all this comment and post about him and I was very sick because I have been infected with HIV/AIDS for the past two year,just last 2 months I keep reading the testimony about this man named Dr Akhigbe they said that the man is so powerful he have cured different type of diseases, I keep monitoring his post of some people about this man and I found out that he was real so I decided to give him a trial I contacted him for help and he said he was going to help me get my cure that all I needed to do was to send him money to prepare the medication after which it will be sent to me via DHL courier delivery services which I did to my greatest surprise the medication was sent to me he gave me instructions to follow on how to drink it that after three weeks I should go for check up,after taking the medicine and follow his instruction after three weeks I went back to the hospital for another test, at first I was shocked when the doctor told me that I was negative I ask the doctor to check again and the result was still the same negative that was how I free from HIV VIRUS at of the shock I decided to come and share my own testimony with you for those who think there is no cure for HIV VIRUS the cure as finally come' out stop doubting and contact Dr Akhigbe via email drrealakhigbe@gmail.com he will help you out you can also whats App him via +2348142454860 he is also perfect in curing DIABETICS,HERPES,HIV/AIDS, ;ALS, CANCER , MALARIA , BACTERIA DIARRHEA, MENINGITIS,HEPATITIS A AND B,ASTHMA, HEART DISEASE, CHRONIC DISEASE. NAUSEA VOMITING OR DIARRHEA, KIDNEY DISEASE,, SCHIZOPHRENIA, LUPUS,EXTERNAL INFECTION, COMMON COLD, JOINT PAIN, OSTEOPOROSIS, RABIES RHEUMATISM, THYROID, GALLSTONE, COLD & FLU, DENGUE, HUNTINGTON'S DISEASE, PROSTATE, CIRRHOSIS, DENGUE FEVER, SCABIES, EPILEPSY,STROKE,TUBERCULOSIS ,STOMACH DISEASE. ECZEMA, SMALLPOX, PROGERIA, EATING DISORDER, LOWER RESPIRATORY INFECTION. etc believe me that deadly disease is not longer a deadly sentence because dr akhigbe has the cure.the godfather of herbal root.email: drrealakhigbe@gmail.com whatsapp number. +2349010754824 website: https://drrealakhigbe.weebly.com
ReplyDelete